Your Right to Fish for Food
![Promote option4](../images/gr_promote.gif)
![Please help option4](../images/gr_support.gif)
| ![](../images/spacer.gif) |
![](../images/spacer.gif) |
Kahawai Final Advice Paper
Ministry
of Fisheries
29
June 2004
Loss of economic return
- While there might be a number of possible economic effects from
setting TACs at the level proposed in the IPP those that were
quantifiable were minor. Lost opportunity costs (associated with
the limitation on expansion of commercial catch) needed to be
weighed against the uncertainty in current stock status, the value
of kahawai as a shared fishery and the importance of this species
in an ecological context.
- MFish has evaluated the potential economic impact of TACC options
on Industry in more detail.
Restructuring
costs
- There are short-term impacts arising from introducing kahawai
into the QMS associated with the need for individual fishers to
acquire quota to reflect their current fishing operations. Kahawai
landings in the criteria years for catch history were substantially
higher than they are currently. This has led to a situation where
the sum of provisional catch history exceeds most of the proposed
TACCs for kahawai stocks. Unless provisional catch history is
cancelled (this occurs if it is not transferred) current fishers
who were also fishing during the criteria years will have their
provisional catch history reduced. The level of reduction is dependent
on the TACC that is finally set. For any of the TACC options proposed
there is likely to be a reduction in provisional catch history
(that is provisional catch history will transfer to a smaller
share of actual quota). Accordingly once quota is allocated, some
current fishers may hold insufficient quota to cover kahawai landings
from their current fishing operations.
- However, under a QMS regime the balancing regime will require
fishers landing kahawai without annual catch entitlement (ACE)
to pay the deemed value. Differential deemed values are also proposed.
Those fishers consistently landing kahawai, particularly those
landing kahawai as an unavoidable bycatch, will place a greater
value on quota to avoid a future stream of deemed value payments.
This will create an incentive for quota to flow to those fishers
with a long-term interest in the fishery. MFish expects that there
will be short-term restructuring costs for these long-term fishers
while quota is repositioned to where it is most required and valued.
A similar situation (and impact) is anticipated for new entrants
to target fisheries of which kahawai is a bycatch who will receive
no allocation of kahawai quota.
Reference points
- MFish has used reference points to compare the socio-economic
impacts of TACC options as follows:
- Current utilisation; and
- Average bycatch.
- The MFish estimate of current commercial utilisation forms the
basis of the status quo fishery. Accordingly it is a useful reference
point for TACC options proposed.
- A further reference point for any potential economic impact
is the constraint a shortage of ACE for bycatch species might
impose on target fisheries. Kahawai bycatch at moderate levels
is associated with target fishing for jack mackerels, trevally,
snapper and grey mullet. The level of bycatch reported has been
relatively stable over the past ten years in KAH1 and KAH 3. Accordingly,
MFish considers that in these areas the difference between total
commercial kahawai landings and those reported as caught when
targeting kahawai might represent a minimum level in terms of
a manageable bycatch.
- Recently reported bycatch levels are based on current fishing
methods in use in the fishery. As most of the bycatch of kahawai
is in the purse seine fishery for jack mackerels and the trawl
fisheries for trevally and snapper incidental bycatches of kahawai
can probably not be actively managed by fishers.
- In KAH 2 and KAH 8 the level of reported bycatch is more variable
between years. However, only in KAH 8 is the average level of
bycatch greater than the target catch.
Estimates of loss
of economic return
- MFish has estimated the potential loss of economic return with
respect to the reference points above for each of the following
factors:
- loss in earnings from kahawai (based on port price);
- loss in quota value; and
- potential deemed value costs.
- Commercial impacts can be measured as direct opportunity costs.
A tonne of kahawai has a value and any reduction in tonnage for
the commercial sector as a result of a lower TACC can be measured
as an opportunity cost. MFish considers that impacts can best
be measured by asset value and by forgone annual earnings as provided
by the port price of kahawai (MFish notes that port prices will
overestimate annual earnings as these include handling costs).
- In the IPP asset value (quota value) for kahawai was estimated
between $1 700 and $5 100. MFish accepts that there is uncertainty
in estimations of the future quota price for kahawai but in the
absence of any alternative asset values provided by submissions,
consider these to be the best available information.
- MFish has evaluated loss of economic return for three TACC options
against points of comparison. These are:
- The Sanford option;
- Proportional reduction option; and
- Non-Commercial Fishers option
- Sanford has submitted that it prefers that the MCY estimate
of 8 200 tonnes be used as the basis of setting TACCs after allowances
are made for non-commercial fishing. MFish has used the industry
proposal as a point of comparison to evaluate TACC options and
assess the potential impacts of the TACC options proposed. MFish
notes that within that level of TAC Sanford proposes greater TACCs
than other options.
- The Proportional Reduction TACC option is based on an arbitrary
15% reduction from current commercial levels of use. MFish has
used the alternative MFish proposal as a point of comparison to
evaluate TACC options and assess the potential impacts of the
TACC options proposed.
- Non-Commercial Fishers has submitted that it prefers that a
revised MCY estimate of 6 900 tonnes be used as the basis of setting
TACCs after allowances are made for non-commercial fishing. MFish
has used the recreational proposal as a point of comparison to
evaluate TACC options and assess the potential impacts of the
TACC options proposed.
- Taking the difference between each TACC option and the reference
point and multiplying this difference by the port price of $0.85
for all stocks estimates the forgone annual earnings associated
with each TACC option.
- Taking the difference between each TACC option and the reference
point and multiplying by the estimate of quota value per tonne
for all stocks estimates the potential forgone quota value. As
mentioned above the quota value is estimated to range between
$1 700 and $5 100
- For associated fisheries, economic impacts can occur when ACE
is not available to cover the inevitable bycatch associated with
other target fisheries. Impacts include the payment of deemed
values for any kahawai taken above ACE.
- The potential for costs associated with payment of deemed values
is estimated from taking the difference between each TACC option
and the average bycatch and multiplying by the proposed deemed
values of $610 or 660 per tonne. MFish notes that this assessment
is based on the fishery as a whole. The potential for deemed value
costs is further influenced by the circumstances of individual
fishers with respect to their future quota holdings of kahawai.
MFish notes that this analysis is based on the payment of annual
deemed values and does not apply to differential deemed value
rates. If differential deemed value rates are incurred the impacts
could be up to two fold greater.
- An alternative to the payment of deemed value when there is
insufficient ACE to cover bycatch is that fishers could stop fishing
for their target species. MFish is not aware of any current situation
where the landing of target species is constrained by the level
of bycatch TACCs. Typically when landings are taken in excess
of the bycatch TACC deemed values are paid. Accordingly, MFish
does not consider there will be any potential costs of foregone
fishing for associated species due to kahawai bycatch limitations.
- The assessment of the potential loss of economic return associated
with TACC options is summarised in Table 10.
Conclusion
- MFish notes that adopting the current utilisation option imposes
no costs greater than reference points.
- MFish concludes that restructuring costs above what may be usual
for a QMS introduction are likely for kahawai because historical
catch (and therefore PCH) is higher than any TACC option proposed.
MFish considers that these costs will be short term but are relevant
for you to consider. MFish notes that fishers will incur restructuring
costs under any of the TACC options proposed.
- Assessing loss of economic return for kahawai TACC options is
problematic. MFish has therefore provided a range of reference
points for you to consider with respect to the choice of TACC
options. MFish has used port prices and derived an asset value
(quota price) to assess opportunity costs of TACC options with
respect to these reference points. Because no quota market currently
exists for kahawai, the assessment has relied on proxy values.
MFish notes that there is uncertainly associated with this approach,
however it is considered the best information currently available.
- MFish notes that adopting the Sanford option will increase economic
returns in comparison to current levels of utilisation.
- Adopting the proportional reduction option will result in forgone
port price earnings and quota value of 15% in comparison to current
utilisation. In addition, MFish notes that adopting a proportional
reduction of commercial catches in KAH 8 reduces the TACC below
the average landings of bycatch. This would mean incurring the
payment of deemed values for this overcatch. The level of bycatch
is variable and catches have exceeded the proposed TACC in only
four of the past fifteen years. Nevertheless, on average deemed
value payments of $58 000 per annum might be expected by adopting
TACCs that are proportionally reduced.
- MFish concludes that apart from forgoing annual economic returns
and asset values with respect to setting TACCs at the greater
values of the Sanford and current utilisation options, the only
other impact incurred by setting TACCs at the level of the proportional
reduction option is in KAH 8, where deemed values may be occurred
from over catching kahawai as a bycatch in some years.
- Adopting the Non-Commercial Fishers option will result in concomitant
forgone port prices and quota value of about 25% in comparison
to current utilisation. In addition, MFish notes that adopting
this proposal would reduce the TACC below the average landings
of bycatch in KAH 2, KAH 3 and KAH 8. This would mean incurring
the payment of deemed values for this overcatch.
TOP
Allowances for other sources of mortality
MFish initial
position
- The IPP proposed setting a nominal allowance of 5% of the average
reported purse seine landings for the last five years in accordance
with the legislative requirement to provide an allowance for other
sources of fishing related mortality.
Submissions
- Sanford submits that purse seine fishing is a benign method
because fish are alive until they are in the hold of the vessel.
As a result any catch can be released from the net in the event
of gear problems. Accordingly, it submits that an allowance for
fishing-related mortality is unnecessary.
- Non-Commercial Fishers submit that set netting and other commercial
methods result in incidental mortality of kahawai. It recommends
other sources of fishing related mortality be set on the basis
of 5% of all commercial methods.
- Richard Pollock submits that illegal selling of kahawai is a
common occurrence and should be provided for by way of this allowance.
MFish response
- The IPP proposal was based on a nominal value for one particular
method of commercial fishing. MFish does not agree with Sanford
that purse seining is completely benign and in the event of gear
problems all fish are unharmed. Reports suggest that schools sometimes
merge dragging the gear under water and allowing kahawai to escape.
The trauma associated with this is likely to cause incidental
mortality. MFish notes the submission of Non-Commercial Fishers
that other commercial methods also result in incidental mortality.
However, MFish believes that any assumptions relating to wider
application of this allowance should also extend to recreational
fishers (that are known to practise catch and release resulting
in further unknown levels of incidental mortality).
- Accordingly, MFish proposes changing the procedures for estimating
other sources of mortality. It proposes setting an arbitrary allowance
for incidental mortality on the basis of 2% of TACs and proposes
to adjust this allowance as new information is obtained. MFish
notes that the level of incidental mortality will vary depending
on the management options being considered and are based on assumptions
that require further investigation.
- The IPP noted at paragraph 53 that there is no information on
the current level of illegal catch. MFish notes Richard Pollock’s
submission that an allowance for this should be made but considers
that this can be incorporated in the generic allowance, which
is now proposed as a proportion of TACs.
|
|